Understanding the Incentives of Commissions Motivated Agents:
Theory and Evidence from the Indian Life Insurance Market
Santosh Anagol
Wharton
Shawn Cole
Harvard Business School
Shayak Sarkar
Harvard University
January 2, 2012
Abstract
We conduct a series of field experiments to evaluate two competing views of the role of
financial service intermediaries in providing product recommendations to potentially uninformed
consumers. One view argues intermediaries provide valuable product education, and guide
consumers towards suitable products. Consumers understand how commissions affect agents’
incentives, and make optimal product choices. The second view argues that intermediaries
recommend and sell products that maximize the agents’ well-being, with little or no regard for
the customer. Audit studies in the Indian life insurance market find evidence supporting the
second view: in 60-80% of visits, agents recommend unsuitable (strictly dominated) products
that provide high commissions to the agents. Customers who specifically express interest in a
suitable product are more likely to receive an appropriate recommendation, though most still
receive bad advice. Agents cater to the beliefs of uninformed consumers, even when those beliefs
are wrong.
We then test how regulation and market structure affect advice. A natural experiment that
required agents to describe commissions for a specific product caused agents to shift recom-
mendations to an alternative product, which had even higher commissions but no disclosure
requirement. We do find some scope for market discipline to generate debiasing: when auditors
express inconsistent beliefs about the product suitable from them, and mention they have re-
ceived advice from another seller of insurance, they are more likely to receive suitable advice.
Agents provide better advice to more sophisticated consumers.
Finally, we describe a model in which dominated products survive in equilibrium, even with
competition.
[email protected]enn.edu, scole@hbs.edu, and ssark[email protected]ard.edu. iTrust provided valuable con-
text on the Indian insurance market for this project. We also thank Daniel Bergstresser, Sendhil Mullainathan, Petia
Topalova, Peter Tufano, Shing-Yi Wang, Justin Wolfers, and workshop participants at Harvard Business School,
Helsinki Finance Summit, Hunter College, the ISB CAF Conference, the NBER Household Finance Working Group,
the NBER Insurance Working Group, Princeton, the RAND Behavioral Finance Forum, and the Utah Winter Fi-
nance Conference for comments and suggestions. We thank the Harvard Lab for Economic and Policy Applications,
Wharton Global Initiatives, Wharton Dean’s Research Fund, Wharton Risk Management and Decision Processes
Center, and the Penn Lauder CIBER Fund for financial support. Manoj Garg, Shahid Vaziralli and Anand Kothari
provided excellent research assistance.
1
1 Introduction
The recent financial crisis has spurred many countries to pursue new consumer financial regulations
that could drastically change the way household financial products are distributed. Both Australia
and the U.K. Financial Services Authority have announced bans, to take effect in 2012, on the
payment of commissions to independent financial advisors.
1
And as of August 2009, the Indian
mutual funds regulator banned mutual funds from collecting entry loads, which had previously
primarily been used to pay commissions to mutual fund brokers.
2
Opponents of these bans argue
that commissions are important to motivate agents to provide financial advice and customer edu-
cation, that competition and reputation concerns will discipline agents, and that consumers have
demonstrated little willingness to pay for independent financial advice.
There is very little evidence to inform these important policy questions. In this paper, we
use a set of field experiments conducted in the Indian life insurance market to provide quantitative
evidence on the quality of advice provided by commissions motivated agents. In addition, we
test recent theories on how commissions motivated agents will respond to disclosure requirements,
greater competition, or more sophisticated consumers.
We focus on the market for life insurance in India for the following reasons. First, given the
complexity of life insurance, consumers likely require help in making purchasing decisions. Sec-
ond, popular press accounts suggest the market may not function well: life insurance agents in
India engage in unethical business practices, promising unrealistic returns or suggesting only high
commission products.
3
Third, the industry is large, with approximately 44 billion dollars of pre-
miums collected in the 2007-2008 financial year, 2.7 million insurance sales agents who collected
approximately 3.73 billion dollars in commissions in 2007-2008, and a total of 105 million insur-
ance customers. Approximately 20 percent of household savings in India is invested in whole life
insurance plans (IRDA, 2010). Fourth, agent behavior is extremely important in this market, as
approximately 90 percent of insurance purchasers buy through agents.
1
Independent Financial Advisors received commissions to sell mutual funds and life insurance products. See
Reuters (2009), Vincent (2009) and Dunkley (2009) for more information on the U.K. ban on commissions. See
“Australia Proposes Ban on Commission” in the Financial Times, September 4, 2011.
2
For newspaper accounts of the importance of entry loads as the primary source of commissions see (1) “MFs
Look For Life Beyond Entry Load Ban,” Times of India, July 19, 2010 (2)“Mutual Fund Industry Struggling to Woo
Retail Investors,” Business Today, February 2011 Edition.
3
See for example, “LIC agents promise 200% return on ’0-investment’ plan,” Economic Times, 22 February 2008.
2
Lastly, commissions motivated sales agents are of particular importance in emerging economies
where a large fraction of the population has little or no experience with formal financial markets.
Commissions may motivate agents to identify potential consumers, educate them about the range
of available products, and identify the most suitable products. Opponents, however, argue that the
commissions motivated agents will encourage consumers to purchase expensive, complicated prod-
ucts that are not necessarily welfare maximizing for households. Systematic empirical evidence is
needed to inform the policy debate about whether commissions motivated agents are necessary for
encouraging the adoption of complicated household financial products.
This project consists of three closely related field experiments. All of these experiments use
an audit study methodology, in which we hired and trained individuals to visit life insurance agents,
express interest in life insurance policies, and seek product recommendations. The goal of the first
set of audits was to test whether, and under what circumstances, agents recommend products
suitable for consumers. In particular, we focused on two common life insurance products: whole life
and term life. We chose these two products because, in the Indian context, consumers are generally
much better off purchasing a term life insurance product than whole life. In section II, we detail
how large this violation of the law of one price can be. The combination of a savings account and
a term insurance policy can provide over six times as much value as a whole life insurance policy.
An important source of friction in financial product markets is that consumers may not know
which products are best for them. A range of evidence suggests that individuals with low levels of
financial literacy make poor investment decisions (Lusardi and Mitchell, 2007). An important role
of agents may be to identify suitable products. In our first experiment, we randomly vary both the
stated belief of the customer as to which product is most suitable, as well information the client
provides about his or her actual needs. Thus, we have some treatments where the customer has
an initial preference for term insurance but where whole insurance is actually the more suitable
product, and vice versa (whole insurance could be a suitable product for an individual who has
difficulty committing to saving). If an agent’s role is to match clients to suitable products, only
the latter information should affect agent recommendations. In fact, we find agents are just as
responsive to consumers self-reported (and incorrect) beliefs as they are to consumers needs.
Interestingly, this is true even when the commission on the more suitable product is higher,
and hence the agent has a strong incentive to de-bias the customer. We view this result as important
3
because it suggests that agents have a strong incentive to cater to the initial preferences of customers
in order to close the sale; contradicting the initial preference of customers, even when they are
wrong, may not be a good sales strategy. Thus, salesmen are unlikely to de-bias customers if they
have strong initial preferences to products that may be unsuitable for them.
Our second, third, and fourth experiments test predictions on how disclosure, competition,
and increased sophistication of consumers affect the quality of advice provided by agents.
In our second experiment, we study whether competition amongst agents can lead to higher
quality advice. We find that that agents who face greater competition, which we induce by having
our auditor state that they have already talked to another agent, leads to better advice. This
evidence is consistent with standard economic models which suggest that, at least under perfect
competition, agents will have an incentive to provide good advice.
In our third experiment we test how disclosure regulation affects the quality of advice provided
by life insurance agents. Mandating that agents disclose commissions has been a popular policy
response to perceived mis-selling. In theory, once consumers understand the incentives faced by
agents, they will be able to filter the advice and recommendations, improving the chance they choose
the product best suited for them, rather than the product that maximizes the agents commissions.
We take advantage of a natural experiment: as of July 1, 2010, the Indian insurance regulator
mandated that insurance agents disclose the commissions they earned on equity linked life insurance
products. We have data on 149 audits conducted before July 1, and 108 audits conducted after
July 1. We find that following the implementation of the regulation, life insurance agents are much
less likely to propose the unit-linked insurance policy to clients, and instead recommend whole life
policies which have higher, but opaque, commissions.
In our last experiment, we test whether the quality of advice received varies by the level of
sophistication the clients demonstrate. We find that less sophisticated agents are more likely to
receive a recommendation for the wrong product, suggesting that agents discriminate in the types
of advice they provide. This result suggests that the selling of unsuitable products is likely to have
the largest welfare impacts on those who are least knowledgeable about financial products in the
first place.
This paper speaks directly to the small, but growing, literature on the role of brokers and
financial advisors in selling financial products. This literature is based on the premise that, in
4
contrast to the market for consumption goods such as pizza, buyers of financial products need
advice and guidance both to determine which product or products are suitable for them, and to
select the best-valued product from the set of products that are suitable.
The theoretical literature can be divided into two strands: one posits that consumers are per-
fectly rational, understand that incentives such as commissions may motivate agents to recommend
particular products, and therefore discount such advice. A second literature argues that consumers
are subject to behavioral biases, and may not be able to process all available information and make
informed conclusions.
Bolton et al. (2007) develops a model in which two intermediaries compete, each offering
two products, one suitable for one type of clients, the other for the other type of clients. While
intermediaries have an incentive to mis-sell, competition may eliminate misbehavior. Inderst and
Ottaviani (2010) show that even in a fully rational world, producers of financial products will pay
financial advisors commissions as a way to incentivize them to learn what products are actually
suitable for their heterogenous customers. Del Guerico and Reuter (2010) take a different tack,
arguing that sellers of mutual fund products in the US that charge high fees may provide intangible
financial services which investors value.
A second, more pessimistic, view, argues that consumers are irrational, and market equilibria
in which consumers make poorly informed decisions may persist, even in the face of competition.
Gabaix and Laibson (2005) develop a market equilibrium model in which myopic consumers sys-
tematically make bad decisions, and firms do not have an incentive to debias consumers. Carlin
(2009) explores how markets for financial products work in which being informed is an endogenous
decision. Firms have an incentive to increase the complexity of products, as it reduces the number
of informed consumers, increasing rents earned by firms. Inderst and Ottaviani (2011) present a
model with naive consumers, where naivete is defined as ignoring the negative incentive effects of
commissions, and find that naive consumers receive less suitable product recommendations.
The theoretical work is complemented by a small, but growing, empirical literature on the
role of competition and commissions in the market for consumer financial products. In a paper
that precedes this one, Mullainathan, Noth, and Schoar (2010) conduct an audit study in the
United States, examining the quality of financial advice provided by advisors. Woodward (2008)
demonstrates mortgage buyers in the U.S. make poor decisions while searching for mortgages. A
5
series of papers (e.g. Choi et al 2009, 2010) demonstrate that consumers fail to make mean-variance
efficient investment decisions, paying substantially more in fees for mutual funds, for example, than
they would if they consistently bought funds from the low-cost provider. In work perhaps most
closely related to this paper, Bergstresser et al. (2009) look at the role of mutual fund brokers in the
United States. They find that funds sold through brokers underperform those sold through other
distribution channels, even before accounting for substantially higher fees (both management fees
and entry/exit fees). Buyers who use brokers are slightly less educated, but by and large similar to
those who do not. They do not find that brokers reduce returns-chasing behavior.
In the next section we describe the basic economics of the life insurance industry in India,
discuss why whole insurance policies are dominated by term policies, and economic theories of why
individuals might still purchase whole policies. Section III discusses the theoretical framework that
guides our empirical tests. Section IV presents the experimental design, while Section V and VI
present our results. In section VII, we describe an equilibrium model of insurance markets in which
dominated products survive, even with competition. Section VIII concludes.
2 Term and Whole Life Insurance in India
Life insurance products may be complicated. In this section, we lay out key differences between
term and whole life insurance products, and demonstrate that the insurance offerings from the
largest insurance company in India violate the law of one price, as long as an individual has access
to a bank savings accounts. Rajagopalan (2010) conducts a similar calculation and also concludes
that purchasing term insurance and saving strictly dominates purchasing whole or endowment
insurance plans.
We start by comparing two product offerings from the Life Insurance Corporation of India
(LIC), the largest insurance seller in India. For many years, LIC was the government-run monopoly
provider of life insurance. We consider the LIC Whole Life Plan (Policy #2), and LIC Term Plan
(Policy #190), for a 25-year old male seeking at least Rs. 2,500,000 in coverage (approximately
USD $50,000), commencing coverage in 2010.
For a whole life policy, such a customer would make 55 annual payments (until the age of
80 is reached) of Rs. 55,116 (ca. $1,110 at 2010 exchange rates). The policy has a face value
6
of Rs. 2,500,000 if the client dies before age 80. In case the client survives until age 80, which
would be the year 2065, the product pays a maturation benefit equal to the coverage amount. The
coverage amount is not necessarily constant: it may be increased via LIC’s “bonus” policy, which
the insurance company may declare if it earns profits. For the past several years, bonuses have
ranged from 6.6% to 7% of the original coverage amount of the insurance policy. Unlike interest or
dividends, these bonus payments are not paid to the client directly. Rather the bonus is added to
the notional coverage amount, paid in case of death of the client, or, at maturity. The insurance
company does not make any express commitment as to whether, and how much, bonus it will offer
in the future.
A critical point to be made here is that the bonus is not compounded.
4
Rather, the bonus
added is simply the amount of initial coverage, multiplied by the bonus fraction. For example,
if the company declares a 7% bonus each year, the amount of coverage offered by the policy will
increase by .07*2,500,000=Rs. 175,000 each year. Thus, after 55 years, when the policy matures,
its face value will be Rs. 2,500,000 + 55*175,000=Rs. 12,125,000.
If these 7 percent bonuses were in fact compounded, the policy would have a face value of Rs.
2,500,000*1.07ˆ55, or over Rs. 103 million, an amount more than eight times larger. Stango and
Zinman (2009) describe evidence from psychology and observed consumer behavior that individuals
have difficulty understanding exponential growth. Consumers who do not understand compound
interest may not appreciate how much more expensive whole life policies are.
A second feature of the two policies may be their relative attractiveness to naive, loss-averse
consumers. Agents frequently dismissed term insurance as an option, arguing that the customer
was likely to live at least twenty years, hence the premiums would be “lost” or “wasted,” while
with whole life the purchaser was guaranteed to get at least the nominal premium paid returned.
In Appendix Table 1, we evaluate the whole life insurance product by creating a replicating
4
It is somewhat surprising that an insurance company has not entered this market and won a substantial amount
of business by offering a whole insurance product that does pay compounded bonuses. In fact, there are some whole
life products that pay a compounded bonus (i.e. the bonus rate is applied to both the sum assured amount plus all
previously accumulated bonus); thus, it is not the case that the insurance industry is unaware that consumers might
like these products. Rather, it seems that it is not possible for an insurance company to win substantial amounts
of business by aggressively selling whole products that pay compounded bonuses. One explanation for this may be
that competition really occurs along the margin of selling effort, as opposed to the quality of the product. In this
case, the products that have highest sales incentives will sell, and any particular insurance firm will have an incentive
to pay the highest commissions on the highest profit products. We present a formal model along these lines that is
consistent with our empirical results later in this paper.
7
portfolio, which consists of a term insurance policy plus savings in a bank fixed deposit account.
Each year, the replicating portfolio provides at least as much coverage (savings plus insurance
coverage) as the whole policy, while requiring the exact same stream of cash flows from the client.
A 25-year old man seeking coverage of Rs. 2,500,000 would pay Rs. 55,116 per year for whole
insurance. If instead he bought a 35-year term policy with Rs. 4,000,000 in coverage, he would
pay Rs. 11,996 each year for 35 years. Over that period, he could save the difference (55,116-
11,996=43,120); once the term policy expired, the replicating portfolio would save Rs. 55,116 per
year. In each year, the death benefit (of term payout, if the policy is active, plus savings) would be
greater than the benefit from the whole policy, including the bonuses. The differences are dramatic:
the initial coverage of the replicating portfolio is Rs. 4 million, vs Rs. 2.5 million for the whole
policy. At age 35, the term plus savings is worth 9% more than the whole payout. By age 55,
the replicating portfolio is worth 36% more than the whole payout, and by age 85 the replicating
portfolio would be worth Rs. 91 million, compared to Rs. 13 million benefit from the whole policy.
The replicating portfolio is almost seven times more valuable.
One argument commonly advanced in favor of whole life insurance is that it provides protec-
tion for the individual’s whole life, and thus eliminates the need to purchase new term insurance
plans in the future. If there is substantial risk that future term insurance premiums might increase
due to increases in the probability of death, then term insurance might be seen as more risky than
whole insurance. However, this argument does not affect our replication strategy, because the term
plus savings plan does not require the individual to purchase another term insurance policy 35
years later.
5
The individual has saved up enough in the savings account to provide self-insurance
after 25 years, which is greater than the amount of insurance that the whole life policy provides.
But even this comparison understates the difference in value dramatically, for at least two
reasons. First, the replicating portfolio builds up a substantial savings balance, which is liquid.
Second, if an individual does not pay each premium promptly, the insurance company has the
right to declare the policy lapsed. Some estimates suggests lapse rates are high: 6% of outstanding
policies lapse in a given year (Kumar, 2009). If the customer lapses after paying premiums for
three or more years, the plan guarantees a recovery value of only 30% of premiums paid (less the
5
Cochrane (1995) discusses this issue in the context of health insurance and proposes an insurance product that
also insures against the risk of future premium increases due to changes in risk.
8
first year’s premiums).
Thus, for an equivalent investment, the buyer receives up to six times as much benefit if she
purchase term plus savings, relative to whole. We are not aware of many violations of the law of
one price that are this dramatic. A benchmark might be the mutual fund industry: $1 invested in
a minimal fee S&P500 fund might earn 8% per annum, and therefore be worth $69 after 55 years.
If an investor invested $1 in a “high cost” mutual fund that charged 2% in fees, the value after 55
years would be $25, or about one third as large. The life insurance mark-up is thus by this metric
twice as large as the mark-up on the highest cost index funds.
2.1 Whole Life Insurance as a Commitment Device
One potential advantage of the whole life policy over term plus savings is that the whole life policy
contains committment features that some consumers value (Ashraf et al. (2006)). The structure
of whole life plans impose a large cost in the case where premium payments are lapsed, and thus
consumers that are sophisticated about their commitment problems may prefer saving in whole life
plans versus standard savings accounts where there are no costs imposed when savings are missed.
In particular, the LIC Whole Insurance Plan No. 2 discussed in the previous section returns nothing
if the policy “lapses’ within the first three years.
However, it is not clear that the commitment feature alone is sufficient to explain the pop-
ularity of whole life insurance. Ashraf et. al. (2006) finds only 25% of the population exhibit
hyperbolic preferences. Moreover, there are other savings products in the Indian context that offer
similar commitment device properties but substantially higher returns. Fixed deposit accounts
involve penalties for early withdrawal. Public provident fund accounts require a minimum of Rs.
500 per year contribution, and allow the saver no access to the money until at least 7 years after the
account is opened. If a saver does not contribute the 500 rupees in a particular year the account
is consider discontinued, and the saver has to pay a 50 rupee fine for each defaulting year plus the
500 rupees that were missed as installments.
Finally, there is no reason a financial services provider could not offer commitment savings
accounts without an insurance component. The fact that no such product has been developed in In-
dia or around the world suggests that this product is not simply satisfying demand for commitment
savings.
9
Nevertheless, we acknowledge that a desire to commit may be relevant for some consumers.
Hence, for any shopping visit in which we regard term insurance as the more appropriate product,
the mystery shopper clearly told the insurance agent that she or he was seeking risk coverage at a
low cost, rather than a savings vehicle.
3 Theoretical Framework
Our empirical work is motivated by recent theoretical work on the provision of advice to potential
customers. Our paper tests two types of predictions that arise from this class of models. The
first set of predictions concerns the quality of advice provided by commissions motivated agents.
These models predict that at least some consumers will receive low quality advice; i.e. they will
be encouraged to purchase an advanced product that has higher commissions but no real benefits
to them (Inderst and Ottaviani, 2011, Gabaix and Laibson, 2005).
6
We test this by measuring the
fraction of agents that recommend customers purchase whole insurance, even in the case where the
customer is only seeking insurance for risk protection (i.e. we shut down any commitment savings
channel).
The second set of predictions relates to how regulation and market structure affect the quality
of advice. We test three predictions from the theoretical literature.
Our first test centers on the role of competition in the provision of advice. Inderst and
Ottaviani (2011) and Bolton et. al. (2007) show that increased competition amongst agents who
provide products and advice can improve the quality of advice for customers. On the other hand,
Gabaix and Laibson (2006) show that increasing competition need not lead firms to unshroud
product characteristics that hurt naive consumers. Our auditors vary the level of competition
perceived by agents, by reporting whether their information about insurance comes from a friend
(low competition), or from another agent from which our auditor is thinking of purchasing insurance
(high competition).
Second, a large literature in economics predicts that competition between firms will induce
6
While the Gabaix and Laibson (2006) paper does not explicitly deal with commissions, it does show that firms
will not necessarily have the incentive to unshroud product attributes (such as commissions or low rates of return in
our case) because unshrouding these will not necessarily win the firm business. In our case, the analogy would be
that life insurance firms do not have the incentive to unshroud these attributes of whole insurance products because
they would lose a substantial proportion of business to banks and other financial service providers if individuals move
their savings out of life insurance.
10
firms to disclose all relevant information regarding products (Diamond (1985), Grossman (1989)).
In these models, mandatory disclosure enforced by the government does not change consumer
decisions and does not improve welfare. However, Inderst and Ottaviani (2011) argue that disclosure
requirements can improve the quality of advice by essentially converting unaware customers into
customers that are aware of how commissions can bias advice. We test how a disclosure requirement
on commissions impacts financial advice by studying a particular type of insurance product, a Unit
Linked Insurance Policy (ULIP), where agents were forced to disclose the commissions they earned
after July 1, 2010.
Lastly, a key feature of the recent theoretical models in Inderst and Ottaviani (2011) and
Gabaix and Laibson (2006) is the presence of two types of agents, with different levels of sophis-
tication. Inderst and Ottaviani (2011) predict that these sophisticated types will receive better
advice. We test this prediction by inducing variation in the level of sophistication demonstrated
by the agent during the sales visit.
4 Experimental Design
4.1 Setting
In this section we describe the basic experimental setup common to the three separate experiments
we ran in this study. All of the auditors used have at least a high school education. Intensive
introductory training on life insurance was provided by a former financial products sales manager,
and a principal investigator. Subsequently, each auditor was trained in the specific scripts they
were to follow when meeting with the agents. Each agent’s script was customized to match the
agents true life situation (number of children, place of residence, etc.). However, agents were
given uniform and consistent language to use when asking about insurance products, and seeking
recommendations. Auditors memorized the scripts, as they would be unable to use notes in their
meetings with the agents. Following each interview, auditors completed an exit interview form
immediately, which was entered and checked for consistency. The auditors and their manager were
told neither the purpose of the study, nor the specific hypotheses we sought to test.
Auditors were instructed not to lie during any of the sessions. Upon completion of the study,
all auditors were given a cash bonus which they used to purchase a life insurance policy from the
11
agent of their choice. All of our auditors chose to purchase term insurance.
In each experiment, treatments were randomly assigned to auditors, and auditors to agents.
Note that because the randomizations were done independently, this means that each auditor did
not necessarily do an equivalent number of treatment and control audits for any given variable of
interest (i.e. sophistication and/or competition). Table 1 presents the number of audits, number
of auditors, and number of life insurance agents for each separate treatment cell in each of our
three experiments. Since we were identifying agents as the experiment proceeded, we randomized
in daily batches. To ensure treatment fidelity, auditors were assigned to use only one particular
treatment script on a given day.
Life insurance agents were identified via a number of different sources, most of which were
websites with national listings of life insurance agents.
7
Contact procedures were identical across
the treatments. While some agents were visited more than once, care was taken to ensure no
auditor visited the same agent twice, and to space any repeat visit at least four weeks apart, both
to minimize the burden on the agents, and to reduce the chance the agent would learn of the study.
Table 2 presents summary statistics across the three experiments we report results on in
this paper. The Quality of Advice experiment was conducted in one major Indian city, and the
Disclosure and Sophistication experiments were conducted in second major Indian city.
8
Across
the experiments, between 50-75% of agents visited sold policies underwritten by the Life Insurance
Company of India (LIC), a state owned life insurance firm. This fraction is consistent with LIC’s
market share, which was 66 percent of total premiums collected in 2010.
In terms of the location of the interaction between the auditor and the life insurance agent, one
major difference between the Quality of Advice experiment and the Disclosure and Sophistication
experiments is that a substantial number of Quality of Advice audits occurred at venues outside
the agent’s office. These other locations were typically a restaurant, cafe, railway or bus station, or
public park. In the Disclosure and Sophistication experiments, the majority of audits took place
at the agent’s office. On average, each audit lasted about 35 minutes, suggesting these audits do
represent substantial interactions between our auditors and the life insurance agents. The length
7
We also included a small number of agents we found through outdoor advertisements and through a listing of
Life Insurance Corporation of India agents.
8
The Competition experiment was conducted as a sub-treatment within the Quality of Advice experiment, and
thus shares the same summary statistics.
12
of audit did not vary substantially across the different experiments.
Matched pair audit studies used to identify discrimination have been criticized on method-
ological grounds. These studies, which involve sending, for example, black and white car buyers to
purchase a car. Critics argue that even if auditors stick to identical scripts, they may exhibit other
differences (apparent education, income, etc.) that could lead sales agents to treat buyers differently
for reasons other than the buyer’s race or sex (Heckman, 1998). While our study is not subject
to this criticism–our treatments were randomized at the auditor level, so we can include auditor
fixed effects–we took great care to address other potential threats to internal validity. Outright
fraud from our auditors is very unlikely, as they were obliged to hand in business cards of the sales
agents. To monitor script compliance, we paid insurance agents within the principal investigators’
social network to “audit the auditors”–these agents reported that our auditors adhered to scripts.
The outcome we measure, policy recommended, is relatively straightforward, and auditors were
instructed to ask the agent for a specific recommendation. To prevent auditor demand effects, we
did not inform the auditors of the hypotheses we were interested in testing.
5 Quality of Advice
5.1 Quality of Advice: Catering to Beliefs Versus Needs
In this experiment we test the sensitivity of agents’ recommendations to the actual needs of con-
sumers, as well as to consumers potentially incorrect beliefs about which product is most appro-
priate for them. In particular, one reason agents may recommend whole insurance is a belief that
customers will value the commitment savings features. To examine this, we vary the expressed need
of the agent, by assigning them one of two treatments. In half of the audits, the auditor signals
a need for a whole insurance policy by stating: “I want to save and invest money for the future,
and I also want to make sure my wife and children will be taken care of if I die. I do not have
the discipline to save on my own.” Good advice under this treatment might plausibly constitute
the agent recommending whole insurance. In the other half of the audits, the auditor says “I am
worried that if I die early, my wife and kids will not be able to live comfortably or meet our financial
obligations. I want to cover that risk at an affordable cost.” In this case the auditor demonstrates
a real need for term insurance. By comparing agent recommendations across these two groups, we
13
can measure whether agent recommendation responds to agents true needs. Appendix Table A2
presents the exact wording of all of the experimental treatments in this study.
We also randomized the customer’s stated beliefs about which product was appropriate for
him or her. In audits where the auditor was to convey a belief that whole insurance was the correct
product for them, the auditor would state “I have heard from [source] that whole insurance may
be a good product for me. Maybe we should explore that further?” In the audits where the auditor
was to convey a belief that term insurance was the correct product for them, the auditor would
state ”I have heard from [source] that whole insurance may be a good product for me. Maybe we
should explore that further?”
Finally, to understand the role of competition, we also varied the source auditors mentioned
when talking about their beliefs. In the low competition treatment, the auditor named a friend as a
source of the advice. In the high competition treatment, the auditor said the suggestion had come
from another agent from whom the auditor was considering purchasing.
Each of these three treatments (product need, product belief, and source of information) was
assigned orthogonally, so this experiment includes eight treatment groups.
Table 3 presents a randomization check to see if there are important differences in the audits
that were randomized into different groups. The first two columns compare audits that were ran-
domized such that the auditor had either a bias for term (Column (1)) or a bias for whole (Column
(2)). As would be expected given the randomization, there are almost no systematic differences
across the two groups. The only significant difference is that audits assigned a bias towards whole
were approximately two percentage points more likely to be conducted at the auditor’s home. We
include audit location fixed effects in our specifications and find they do not substantially change
the results.
Columns (3) and (4) present characteristics of audits where the auditor was randomized into
having a need for term insurance (Column (3)) or a need for whole insurance (Column (4)). The
next two columns present the pre-treatment characteristics of audits where the source of the bias
was another agent (Column (5)) or a friend (Column (6)). There are also no statistically significant
differences in the pre-audit characteristics across these groups.
9
9
Throughout the paper, we use robust standard errors; results and significance levels are virtually identical if we
cluster standard errors at the level of randomization, auditor*day.
14
Before describing the experimental results, we emphasize how poor the quality of advice is: for
individuals for whom term is the most suitable product, only 5% of agents recommend purchasing
only term insurance, while 74% recommend purchasing only whole. A previous version of this paper
documented a range of wildly incorrect statements made by agents, such as “term insurance is not
for women;” “term insurance is for government employees only.” One even proposed a policy that
he described as term insurance, which was in fact whole insurance.
Table 4 presents our main results on how variation in the needs of customers and biases
of customers affect the quality of financial advice.
10
Column (1) presents results on whether the
agent’s final recommendation included a term insurance policy (in about 8% of the cases, agents
recommend the consumer purchase multiple products). We find that agents are 10 percentage
points more likely to make a final recommendation that includes a term insurance policy if the
auditor states that they have heard term insurance is a good product. We also find that agents are
12 percentage points more likely to make a recommendation that includes a term insurance policy
if the auditor says they are looking for low-cost risk coverage. Both of these results are statistically
significant at the 1 percent level. The interaction of these two variables is statistically insignificant.
This suggests that agents are just as likely to cater to beliefs as needs.
In column (2), we add auditor-fixed effects and controls for venue and whether the agent sells
policies underwritten by a government-owned insurer. The experimental results are unaffected.
Agents from the government owned insurance underwriters (primarily the Life Insurance Corpora-
tion of India) are 12 percentage points less likely to recommend a term insurance plan as a part of
their recommendation.
Column (3) presents the same exact specification as Column (1), however now the dependent
variable takes a value of one if the agent recommended only a term insurance plan. We find
much weaker results here. A customer stating that they have heard that term insurance is a good
product is only 2 percentage points more likely to receive a recommendation to only purchase term
insurance. We find that stating a need for affordable risk coverage only causes a 1.5 percentage
point increase in the probability that the agent will recommend exclusively term insurance. This
effect is not statistically significant at conventional levels. When the auditor both states that they
10
In this section we focus on the quality of advice given, and thus report results on how advice responds to a
customer’s needs versus beliefs. Later, we discuss the impact of the competition treatment when we focus on how
quality of advice might be improved.
15
need risk coverage and they have heard that term is a good product we find an increase of 5.3
percentage points, significant at the ten percent level. Column (4) adds controls.
Thus, comparing Columns (2) and (4) it appears that agents do respond to both the biases
and needs of customers, however, they primarily do it by recommending term insurance products
as an addition to whole insurance products, rather than recommending the purchase of term.
Overall, the results in Columns (1) - (4) suggest that agents will respond approximately
equally to both the needs and pre-existing biases of customers. These results are consistent with
the idea that agents maximize the expected revenue from an interaction, and the expected revenue
depends both on the probability that the customer will purchase as well as the amount of commission
that can be earned. Agents do not seem to attempt to de-bias customers who express perceived
needs inconsistent with actual needs; thus, in this context it seems unlikely that commissions
motivated agents are effective in undoing behavioral biases customers bring to their insurance
purchase decisions.
Columns (5) and (6) shows that stating an initial bias towards term insurance causes the
agent to recommend the customer purchase approximately 13 percent more risk coverage, while
expressing a need for risk coverage increases the recommended risk coverage by 17 percentage
points. Both of these effects are significant at the five percent level, but their interaction is not.
Again, these results suggest agents will cater approximately equally to the stated preferences of
a customer (even if those preferences are inconsistent with their actual needs), about as much as
they cater to the actual stated needs of customers.
Columns (7) and (8) test whether the recommended premium amounts are statistically differ-
ent across the treatments. We find that the bias and need treatments have small and statistically
insignificant effects on the level of premiums the agent recommends that customers pay to pur-
chase insurance. This suggests that although agents are recommending higher coverage levels for
those who either have a bias towards term or a need for term (Columns (5) and (6)), customers
are not paying higher premiums to obtain this additional coverage. Instead, the increase in risk
coverage observed in Columns (5) and (6) is due primarily to the fact that term insurance provides
dramatically more risk coverage per Rupee of premium.
Further evidence of this interpretation is obtained from the average amounts of risk coverage
and premium amounts when agents recommended term versus whole insurance (not reported). In
16
the case where the auditor sought risk coverage at an affordable cost and said they had heard risk
coverage was a good product for them, agents recommending term insurance proposed 2.3 million
rupees of risk coverage, with an annual premium cost of approximately 31,000 rupees. Agents
recommending whole insurance suggested customers purchase 522,000 rupees of risk coverage, with
an annual premium of approximately 28,000 rupees. Our auditors characteristics (income, depen-
dents) are the same no matter what beliefs they express, meaning there is no economic reason to
suggest greater coverage levels when the auditor expresses a preference for coverage at low cost.
One explanation for this result, consistent with the bad advice hypothesis, is that agents base their
recommendations on the amount of premiums customers can pay, as opposed to the amount of risk
coverage customers actual need. Our finding here is consistent with anecdotal evidence from dis-
cussions with our auditing team: agents typically start the life insurance conversation by estimating
how much the individual can afford to put into life insurance per month, rather than determining
how much risk coverage the customer needs.
In summary, we find the following. Despite the fact term is an objectively better policy,
between 60 and 80 percent of our visits end with a recommendation that the customer purchase
whole life insurance. Second, even when customers signal that they are most interested in term
insurance and need risk coverage, more than 60 percent of audits result in whole insurance being
recommended. Third, we find that agents primarily cater to customers (either their beliefs or needs)
by recommending that they purchase term insurance in addition to whole insurance, as opposed to
recommending term insurance alone. It is difficult to see how combining term and whole insurance
makes sense for someone who is seeking risk coverage.
6 Financial Advice and Market Structure
These previous results are consistent with the models of Inderst and Ottaviani (2011), Gabaix and
Laibson (2006) and Bolton et al. (2007) which suggest commissions motivated sales agents will have
an incentive to recommend more complicated, but potentially unsuitable, products to customers
who are not wary of the agency problems that commissions create (at least under some market
structures). In this section we turn to testing theoretical predictions on how advice responds to the
regulatory and market structure. As our experimental design allows us to measure the type of advice
17
given, we focus on three predictions. First, the threat of increased competition from another agent
will reduce the probability an unsuitable product is recommended. Second, increasing consumers
awareness of commissions will reduce the tendency to recommend unsuitable products. Third,
agents will provide different advice to sophisticated versus unsophisticated consumers.
6.1 Competition
One way agents may compete with each other is to offer better financial advice. Standard models
of information provision suggest that competition amongst advice providers will lead to the op-
timal advice being given; customers will avoid salesmen who give low quality advice and thus in
equilibrium only high quality advice will be given.
In any given interaction between an agent and a customer, it is likely that the agent perceives
he has some market power, in that the customer would have to pay additional search costs to
purchase from another agent. In this treatment we attempted to experimentally reduce the agent’s
perceived amount of market power by varying whether the customer mentions that they have
already spoken to another agent. Audits randomized into the high competition treatment stated
that they heard from another agent term (or whole) might be a good product for them. Audits
randomized into the low competition treatment state that they heard from a friend that term (or
whole) might be a good product for them.
The audits for which these data are based on are the same as those used in the Quality of
Advice experiment. Table 5 presents our results on the impact of greater perceived competition
on the quality of advice provided by life insurance agents. The specifications reported here are the
same as those in Table 4, but we now introduce a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the
auditor’s bias came from a competing agent, and zero if the bias came from a friend. Columns
(1) and (2) show that overall the induced competition does not seem to have an important effect
on whether agents recommend term insurance as part of their package recommendation. Columns
(5) and (6) show that the competition treatment also did not have an overall increasing effect on
whether only a term policy was recommended.
Columns (3) and (4) introduce a set of interaction terms between the bias treatment, the
need treatment, and the competition treatment. We are particularly interested in the treatment
where the customer is biased towards whole insurance but demonstrates a need for term insurance.
18
In this setting the agent has the potential to “de-bias” the auditor as their beliefs are inconsistent
with their insurance needs. In Columns (3) and (4) we find that the agent is substantially more
likely to debias agents when the threat of competition looms. This effect is measured by summing
the coefficients on the variables Competition and (Need=Term)*Competition. The sum suggests
agents advising customers who need term but are biased towards whole are 10 percent more likely
to recommend term insurance if they perceive higher levels of competition. The hypothesis that
(Need=Term)*Competition + Competition = 0 can be rejected at the 5% level. This result suggests
that if perceived competition is high enough, agents will attempt de-bias customers as a way of
winning business.
We do not, however, find that competition increases the possibility that agents will de-bias
customers who have a belief that term insurance is a good product but need help with savings.
We find that the coefficient on the interaction (Bias=Term)*Competition is small and statistically
insignificant.
Columns (7) and (8) report the same specification as those in Columns (3) and (4), however
the dependent variable takes the value of one if the agent recommended the customer purchase
only term insurance. We do not find any evidence that agents attempt to de-bias consumers
by recommending they only purchase term insurance. The coefficient on the interaction term
(Need=Term)*Competition is small and insignificant in Columns (7) and (8). We find that the
competition treatment is only effective, in this case, when the agent has both a bias and a need
towards term insurance. One interpretation of this result is that agents assume that a customer
who has the knowledge to know that term insurance is the best product for someone who needs
risk coverage is almost surely going to purchase term insurance from the other agent. Thus, the
agent in the audit chooses to compete by recommending only a term insurance purchase as well.
6.2 Disclosure
On July 1, 2010, the Indian Insurance Regulator mandated that insurance agents must disclose
the commissions they would earn when selling a specific type of whole insurance product called a
ULIP. ULIPs are very similar to whole insurance policies, except the savings component is invested
in equity instruments with uncertain returns. This regulation was enacted as the Indian insurance
regulator faced criticism from the Indian stock market regulator that ULIPs should be regulated
19
in the same was as other equity based investment products. The insurance regulator responded to
these criticisms by requiring agents to disclose commissions when selling ULIPs.
There are two specific features of this policy we emphasize before discussing our empirical
results. First, it is important to note that the disclosure of commissions required on July 1st is
in addition to a disclosure requirement on total charges that came into effect earlier in 2010. In
other words, prior to July 1, agents were required to disclose the total charges (i.e. the total costs,
including commissions) of the policies they sell, but they were not required to disclose how much
of those charges went to commissions versus how much went to the life insurance company. Thus,
the new legislation requiring the specific disclosure of commissions gives the potential life insurance
customer more information on the agency problem between himself and the agent, but does not
change the amount of information on total costs. This allows us to interpret our results as the effect
of better information about agency, rather than better information about costs more generally.
To focus the visits on ULIPs, agents began by inquiring specifically about ULIP products
available. The experimental design here involves two components. First, we conducted audits before
and after this legal change to test whether the behavior of agents would change due to the fact that
they were forced to disclose commissions. Second, we also randomly assigned each of these audits
into two groups, where in one group the auditor conveys knowledge of commissions and in the other
group the auditor does not mention commissions. We created these two treatments as we believed
only customers who have some awareness of these commissions were likely to be affected by this law
change. In one group, we had the auditor explicitly mention that they were knowledgeable about
commissions by stating: “Can you give me more information about the commission charges I’ll be
paying?” In the control group, the auditor did not ask this question about commission charges.
Table 6 presents summary statistics on the disclosure experiment audits. Column (1) pertains
to the full sample audits, while (2) and (3) present summary statistics on the audits before and
after the regulation went into effect. There are several differences between the pre- and post-
audits. In particular, post disclosure change audits were more likely to be conducted with the Life
Insurance Company of India, and the meetings took place in different venues. These differences
suggest that caution is warranted when comparing the pre- and post- results. Columns (7) and
(8) of Table 3 present summary statistics on the randomization of the different levels of knowledge
about commissions.
20
6.3 Did the Disclosure Requirement Change Products Recommended?
We first examine whether audits conducted after the disclosure requirements went into effect were
less likely to result in the agent recommending a ULIP policy. Figure 1 shows the weekly average
fraction of audits that resulted in a ULIP recommendation. Prior to the commissions disclosure
reform, agents recommended ULIPs eighty to ninety percent of the time. Following the reform,
there is an immediate and discrete drop in the fraction recommending ULIPs, to between forty and
sixty-five percent of audits. The discrete jump suggests the observed differences are driven by the
disclosure requirement, rather than being attributable to a steady downtrend trend in the fraction
of agents recommending ULIP policies over time.
Table 7 presents the formal empirical results. The dependent variable in all specifications
in this table takes a value of one if the agent recommended a ULIP product and zero otherwise.
The independent variable Post Disclosure indicates whether or not the audit occurred after the
legislation went into effect, July 1st (our earliest post-disclosure audits occurred on July 2nd). The
variable Disclosure Knowledge equals one where the client expresses awareness that agents receive
commissions and zero otherwise. Finally, we control for whether the agent is from a government
underwriter, auditor fixed effects, and the location of the audit.
Column (1) presents a regression without controls. We find that in the post period a ULIP
product was 25 percentage points less likely to be recommended. This finding is consistent with
the prediction that agents treat customers who are concerned about commissions differently than
those who are not, and that disclosure policy can improve customer awareness. We do not find
the randomized treatment of the auditor demonstrating knowledge of the commissions significant
(Disclosure Knowledge), nor do we find the interaction to be significant.
One potential threat to the validity of our analysis is the change in composition of agents
between the pre- and post-period. Perhaps most important is the difference between the fraction
of agents selling policies issued by government-owned insurance companies before and after the law
change. In Column (2), we control for whether the agent works for a government-run insurance
company, as well as location and auditor fixed-effects. The point estimate is slightly smaller, but
the effect is still quite sizeable at 19 percentage points.
In columns (3) and (4) we examine agents for government-owned and private insurance com-
21
panies seperately. Among those selling policies underwritten by government-owned companies,
there is a 30 percent decrease in the likelihood of recommending a ULIP policy after the disclosure
law becomes effective. Amongst private underwriters, we find a negative point estimate, although
the coefficient is not significant at standard levels. The result in Column (3) suggests that the
observed reduction in ULIP recommendations in the whole sample is not driven by a compositional
shift in the types of agents the auditors meet.
In terms of magnitudes, given the overall percentage of ULIP recommendations in this sample
was 71 percent, the approximately 20 percent decrease in ULIP recommendations once disclosure
commission became mandatory is an economically large effect. Further analysis (not reported)
finds agents were approximately 20 percentage points more likely to recommend whole insurance
type products following the law change. There was no change in their propensity to recommend
term insurance. Thus, it appears that the ULIP disclosure law change primarily led to substitution
away from high commission ULIP products to high commission whole insurance products.
Turning to the experimental treatment, we do not find that audits where our agents showed
knowledge of the new disclosure requirements are associated with lower levels of ULIP recommenda-
tions. The coefficient on the Disclosure Knowledge variable is small and statistically insignificant in
all of the specifications. This treatment does not seem to be affected by the disclosure requirement.
Columns (5) and (6) test whether the commission disclosure requirement had important
impacts on the amount of risk coverage and premium payments recommend by agents. We find no
statistically significant differences here, suggesting that the types of products recommended were
similar in terms of their risk characteristics after the policy change.
6.4 Customer Sophistication
In our final experiment, we manipulated the the level of sophistication about life insurance policies
projected by the auditor. Each auditor was randomly assigned to portray either high or low levels
of sophistication.
Sophisticated auditors say:
“In the past, I have spent time shopping for the policies, and am perhaps surprisingly some-
what familiar with the different types of policies: ULIPs, term, whole life insurance. However, I
am less familiar with the specific policies that your firm offers, so I was hoping you can walk me
22
through them and recommend a policy specific for my situation.”
Unsophisticated agents, on the other hand, state:
“I am aware of the complexities of Life Insurance Products and I don’t understand them very
much; however I am interested in purchasing a policy. Would you help me with this?”
To ensure clarity of interpretation of the suitability of recommendations, we built into the au-
ditors script several statements that suggest a term policy is a better fit for the client. Specifically,
the auditor expressed a desire to maximize risk coverage, and stated that they did not want to use
life insurance as an investment vehicle.
We predict that individuals that are sophisticated about life insurance products will be more
likely to receive truthful information from life insurance agents; agents internalize that sophisticated
agents are not swayed by false claims, and thus presenting dishonest information to sophisticated
agents is wasted persuasive effort. In the specific context of our audits this prediction suggests that
life insurance agents should be more likely to recommend the term policy to sophisticated agents.
Note that we designed our scripts so sophistication here only means that the potential customer is
knowledgeable about life insurance products; both sophisticated and unsophisticated agents state
that they have the same objective needs in terms of life insurance.
Table 3 presents a randomization check for the Sophistication experiment. The only statis-
tically significant different between the sophisticated and non-sophisticated treatments is that the
sophisticated treatments were about eight percentage points less likely to occur at other venues.
Overall, the randomization in this experiment appears to be successful. We control for audit loca-
tion in our results and find this has little impact on the effect of sophistication on recommendations.
The results from the sophistication experiment, reported in Table 8, provide some evidence in
support of our prediction that sophisticated customers will receive better advice. We use the same
specification as in the previous experiments to analyze this data. In Column (1) the dependent
variable takes a value of one if the agent’s recommendation included a term insurance plan, and
zero otherwise. We find that the sophisticated treatment causes a ten percentage point increase
in the likelihood that an agent includes term insurance as a part of their recommendation. This
23
result is statistically significant at the 10 percent confidence level. In Column (2) we include a
set of control variables, the point estimate and confidence interval are virtually unchanged. Thus,
we do see that agents make some attempt to cater to sophisticated individuals by offering term
insurance.
However, in Columns (3) and (4), where the dependent variable takes a value of one if
the agent recommended the auditor purchase only a term a insurance plan, we find there is no
statistically significant effect of sophistication. Similar to the results in the bias versus needs
experiment, it appears that agents attempt to cater to more sophisticated types by including term
as a part of a recommendation. However, they do not switch to recommending only term insurance,
even to customers who signal sophistication.
In Columns (5) and (6) we look at the impact of sophistication on the amount of coverage
recommended by the life insurance agent. Without controls, we find that sophisticated agents
receive guidance to purchase approximately 22 percent more insurance coverage (Column (5)). In
Columns (7) and (8) we test whether sophisticated agents receive different recommendations in
terms of how much premiums they should pay for insurance. We find that signaling sophistication
does not have an important impact on the amount of premiums that agents recommend paying,
although the confidence interval admits economically meaningful effects of up to 25 percent lower
premium costs. Combining the results in Columns (5) - (8), we see that, similar to our results on
coverages and premiums in the other experiments, agents seem to recommend approximately the
same amount of premiums be paid, regardless of our intervention; they cater to customers primarily
by adding a relatively inexpensive term product on top of whole insurance to increase risk coverage
without substantially changing premium payments.
7 A Model of Commissions, Bad Advice, and Dominated Prod-
ucts
We, and others, have argued that whole life insurance is dominated by term insurance for individ-
uals who seek insurance mainly for risk coverage. While the goal of this paper is to understand
commissions motivated agent behavior (rather than offer a competitive analysis of the Indian in-
surance industry), it does raise a puzzle: why do the more expensive, dominated, products, such as
24
whole insurance, persist in a setting with competition? We consider here how a dominated product
could survive, even in a competitive equilibrium.
We present a simple model, inspired by Gabaix and Laibson (2006), which provides one
explanation for how a dominated financial product might exist in competitive equilibrium. The
model takes the empirical results found in this paper, that commissions motivated agents appear
to provide poor financial advice, and shows how it is possible that if at least some consumers are
persuaded by bad advice then it is possible that a dominated product like whole insurance could
persist. The model may be particularly relevant for a country like India with a large number of
new insurance customers entering the market who are still learning about these products and may
be less sensitive to important differences in the long run returns available.
In the model, we focus primarily on the risk coverage offered by the insurance products. The
price of term insurance is the premium, while the “price” of whole insurance should be thought of as
the premium cost minus any savings value that exists beyond the risk coverage. This is equivalent
to assuming whole insurance can be replicated by purchasing term insurance and investing in a
savings account. Thus, the model is set up such that buyers should choose whole insurance only if
the price is cheaper than term insurance. However, we show that an equilibrium is possible where
whole insurance has a higher price than term insurance.
The model has two types of consumers. Sophisticated consumers understand that whole and
term insurance are the same product (and thus would always choose the cheaper one), know their
own optimal amount of insurance, given prices, and are immune to the persuasive efforts of agents.
There is a fixed, exogenous number of sophisticated consumers, s, who want to purchase term
insurance, and each has a demand function for term insurance equal to α p
t
, where p
t
is the
price of term insurance.
Unsophisticated consumers, in contrast, can be persuaded to purchase a dominated product
if there is an agent that exerts enough effort. In particular, we assume unsophisticated agents
demand an amount of insurance α p
w
once they have met with a commissions motivated agent.
Agents must exert effort to identify and sell to unsophisticated consumers. We assume that the
number of customers they find is equal to the commission on selling insurance set by the insurance
company, c. Intuitively, the higher that the insurance firm sets commissions, the more incentive
agents have to approach customers and sell insurance. In addition to commissions payments, the
25
insurance firm incurs an underwriting cost of k per unit of either term insurance or whole insurance
sold.
The game play is as follows. In period 0, the firm(s) choose whether to offer term, whole,
or both insurance products. They also choose the prices p
w
and p
t
and the commissions they will
pay agents to sell whole and term insurance (c
w
, c
t
). In the second period, agents respond to the
incentives set by the insurance companies, and consumers make decisions on how much whole and
term insurance to purchase and insurance. An Appendix contains the proofs of all the results
discussed here.
7.1 Monopolist Insurance Company
A monopolist insurance firm has three possible options (1) offer only term insurance (2) offer whole
and term insurance (3) offer only whole insurance. In the Appendix we show that the monopolist
insurance firm will choose to offer both term and whole insurance. The monopolist firm will pay
zero commissions for the sale of term insurance (as paying commissions on term insurance does not
increase demand) and will charge a price of
α+k
2
for term insurance. The monopolist firm will pay
positive commissions for the sale of whole insurance because demand is increasing in commissions.
The firm will set the whole insurance price (p
w
) equal to
1
3
(2α + k) and will pay commissions
1
3
(α k). Note that as long as α > k (a condition necessary for there to be positive demand for
insurance), that the price of whole insurance will be higher than the price of term insurance.
The intuition for this solution is that offering both term and whole insurance offers the
monopolist firm a way to set different commissions and prices for sophisticated versus unsophisti-
cated customers. Sophisticated consumers cannot be persuaded by commissions motivated agents,
and thus the firm chooses to set commissions to zero and charge lower prices for term insurance.
However, unsophisticated consumers can be persuaded to purchase whole insurance. Thus, the
insurance firm chooses to pay higher commissions to encourage agents to persuade consumers to
purchase insurance, and then passes these higher commissions onto the consumer in terms of higher
prices.
26
7.2 Two Competing Insurance Companies
We now analyze the impact of competition by considering a Bertrand pricing game where two firms
compete by setting term and whole commissions and prices. This game has two players, firm i and
firm j. A strategy in this game consists of (1) a choice of which products to offer (term, whole, or
both) (2) prices and commissions for each product offered. A firm’s payoff function is the profit it
earns given its choice of what products, prices, and commissions to offer as well as the other firm’s
choices.
The payoffs are defined as follows. For term insurance, we use the usual Bertrand pricing game
(with homogenous products) assumption that firm i obtains the full market of all s sophisticated
consumers if p
i
< p
j
(and vice versa). For whole insurance, consumers can be influenced to purchase
both by higher commissions and lower prices. The number of unsophisticated consumers that firm i
sells to given it pays commissions c
i
is c
i
bc
j
. The parameter b, which we assume is always greater
than zero, measures the degree to which firm i and j’s insurance products compete with each other
for customers. If b equals zero then the fact that firm j is paying high commissions does not change
the demand for firm i’s insurance. If b is large, however, then an increase in commissions by firm
j causes a fraction of consumers to switch from firm i’s insurance product to firm j’s product.
Note, however, that once unsophisticated consumers have been persuaded to purchase from a
particular firm because of commissions, the insurance company can charge them the monopoly price.
In this sense, competition for unsophisticated consumers happens primarily through commissions,
and not through prices. The intuition is that unsophisticated consumers respond strongly to the
persuasiveness and effort of agents in choosing what product to buy, but less strongly to the level
of prices.
Bertrand competition over prices in the market for term insurance leads to both firms pricing
term insurance at marginal cost k. In the Appendix we show that the Nash equilibrium commissions
on whole insurance are c
i
= c
j
=
αk
32b
, and the Nash equilibrium prices are p
i
= p
j
=
(2b)α+(1b)k
32b
.
Note that for commissions and prices to be positive we need b
3
2
.
Even though term and whole insurance are the same product in this model, an equilibrium
exists where whole insurance has a higher price than term insurance, and where competition be-
tween firms will not eliminate this dominated product. Analogous to the result in Gabaix and
27
Laibson (2006), a strategy of un-shrouding the whole policy does not work because selling the dom-
inating term policy does not offer the margins necessary to pay large commissions. Thus, it is not
profitable for firms to educate consumers on the fact that whole insurance is simply an expensive
version of term insurance. In equilibrium, firms sell low commission term insurance to sophisticated
consumers, and high commission whole insurance to unsophisticated consumers.
The model also has an interesting prediction on the impact of competition in this market.
When paying commissions causes the competitor to lose more business (b increases), competition
amongst firms leads to an increase in commissions and prices.
11
Thus, when insurance firms
attract customers mainly through commissions, competition can actually lead to higher prices (and
commissions), relative to a monopoly provider. The intuition for this result is that as a monopoly
provider, paying higher commissions loses more in profits due to higher costs than it gains in extra
business. However, when firms compete over commissions, then it becomes necessary to pay higher
commissions to win business, and profits for each sale are lower because more commissions have to
be paid.
We believe this model is a plausible explanation for why a dominated product like whole
insurance can persist in this market. The model fits the basic empirical facts observed in this
market: 1) Term insurance and whole insurance co-exist, although whole insurance can be repli-
cated by term insurance and savings accounts 2) Commissions on whole insurance are substantially
higher than term insurance 3) Agents provide poor advice (i.e do not try to de-bias consumers to-
wards whole insurance) 4) The industry has multiple, seemingly competitive, insurance providers.
Nonetheless, further empirical work is necessary to distinguish the model presented from other po-
tential explanations for the existence of dominated products, such as entry barriers or other market
frictions.
12
8 Conclusion
A critical question facing emerging markets with large swaths of the population entering the formal
financial system is how these new clients will receive good information on how to make financial
11
See appendix for the proof that prices increase.
12
It is important to note that the Indian insurance industry is characterized by significant barriers to entry, including
licensing restrictions and capital requirements, as well as scale economies.
28
decisions. Clearly, the private sector will be important in educating new investors and providing
suitable products. Recent events in developed economies suggest that regulation or improved
consumer awareness may be necessary to ensure that the private sector’s own incentives do not
compromise the quality of financial decisions made by private individuals. This issue is of particular
importance in emerging markets where new investors have little experience with formal financial
products to begin with.
In this paper, we show that whole life insurance is economically inferior to a combination
of investing in savings accounts and purchasing term insurance. Despite the large economic losses
associated with investing in whole insurance we find that life insurance agents overwhelmingly
encourage the purchase of whole insurance.
We then use an audit study to test two types of predictions emerging from recent theoretical
models on commissions and financial advice. The first prediction is that agents will have an
incentive to recommend more expensive, less suitable, products to consumers. Throughout our
three experimental designs, we find that life insurance agents rarely recommend term insurance.
Even in audits where there should be no commitment savings motivation, we still find agents
predominantly recommend whole insurance.
We also find that agents cater to customers’ pre-conceptions of what the right product is
for them as much (if not more) than to objective information about what the right product is.
This suggests that, at least in our sample, agents do not actively try to de-bias customers. This
result holds even in the case where an agent has an incentive to de-bias the customer because a de-
biased customer would purchase a higher commission product. These results suggest that relying
on competition to de-bias consumers of their mis-conceptions may not lead to markets that inform
consumers.
We find that government underwriters are much more likely to recommend the dominated
product. We view the government underwriter result as important. Government ownership is some-
times advanced as a solution to market failures, yet in this setting, agents representing government
underwriters, in particular the Life Insurance Company of India, were much less likely to recom-
mend a suitable product.
We then proceed to test predictions on how changes in the regulatory and market structure
can affect advice given by financial agents.
29
We test the theoretical mechanism that competition amongst agents can lead to better advice.
As mentioned above, the first order fact seems to be that competition does not suffice to motivate
agents to provide good advice in this context. In an experiment,we find that increasing the apparent
level of competition does lead to the agent attempting to de-bias the customer by offering term
insurance. This also suggests that encouraging customers to shop around when looking for consumer
financial products may be a simple way to improve the quality of advice provided by agents.
In another experiment we find that requiring disclosure of commissions on one particular
product led to that product being recommended less. This result is interesting in that it suggests
that hiding information may be an important part of life insurance agents’ sales strategy, and that
disclosure requirements can change the optimal strategy of agents. In this case it appears that the
disclosure requirement on one product simply had the effect of pushing agents to recommend more
opaque products. These results suggest that the disclosure requirements for financial products need
to be consistent across the menu of substitutable products.
Lastly we find that agents who signal sophistication by demonstrating some knowledge of
insurance products get better advice. Auditors that stated they had a deep understanding of
insurance products were 10 percentage points more likely to receive a recommendation that included
term insurance. This result suggests that the worst educated may suffer most from commission-
motivated sales behavior. Further, it suggests that agents may play an important in helping
financial firms discriminate between sophisticated and unsophisticated consumers, which can be
valuable if unsophisticated consumers can be persuaded to purchase dominated products.
We present an equilibrium model where a dominated financial product, such as whole insur-
ance, could persist. The key ingredients of this model are the existence of at least some customers
who can be persuaded to purchase the dominated product; competition amongst firms leads to
agents being paid higher commissions to sell the product, and the higher commissions are passed
on to unsophisticated consumers through higher prices. We believe that this type of model may have
wider applicability across a range of settings where customers are uninformed about the suitability
or value of products.
We believe our study opens some important questions for further research. First, how effective
is the persuasive power of agents? How important are behavioral biases such as loss aversion and
exponential growth bias in driving demand for a dominated product? In the spirit of Bertrand and
30
Morse (2011), could consumers be debiased? The answers to these have important implications for
optimal regulatory policy and household financial decision-making.
9 References
Ashraf, N., D. Karlan and W. Yin. 2006. Tying Odysseus to the Mast: Evidence from a Com-
mitment Savings Product in the Philippines.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(2):
635–672.
Bergstresser, D., J. Chalmers, and P. Tufano. 2009. Assessing the Costs and Benefits of Brokers
in the Mutual Fund Industry. The Review of Financial Studies 22(10):4129–56.
Bertrand, Marianne, and Adair Morse (2011). “Information Disclosure, Cognitive Biases, and
Payday Borrowing,” The Journal of Finance, 66(6): 1865-1893.
Bolton, P., X. Freixas, and J. Shapiro. 2007. Conflicts of Interest, Information Provision, and
Competition in the Financial Services Industry. Journal of Financial Economics 85(2):297–
330.
Carlin, B. 2009. Strategic Price Complexity in Retail Financial Markets. Journal of Financial
Economics 91:278–56.
Choi, J.J., D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, and A. Metrick. 2009. Reinforcement Learning and
Savings Behavior. Journal of Finance 64(6): 2515-34.
Choi, J.J., D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian. 2010. Why Does the Law of One Price Fail? An
Experiment on Index Mutual Funds. Review of Financial Studies 23(4):1–28.
Cochrane, J. 1995. Time-consistent Health Insurance. Journal of Political Economy 103(3):445-
473.
Del Guerico, D., J. Reuter, and P. Tkac. 2010. “Broker Incentives and Mutual Fund Market
Segmentation.” Manuscript, Boston College.
Diamond, D. 1985. Optimal Release of Information by Firms. Journal of Finance 40(4): 1071-94.
31
Gabaix, X., and D. Laibson. 2006. Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information
Suppression in Competitive Markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(2):505–40.
Grossman, S. 1989. The Informational Role of Warranties and Private Disclosure about Product
Quality, In The Informational Role of Prices, edited by Sanford J, Grossman, Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Heckman, James, 1998. Detecting Discrimination, Journal of Economic Perspectives 12(2):101-
116.
Inderst, R., and M. Ottaviani. 2010. Intermediary Commissions and Kickbacks. American
Economic Review, forthcoming.
Inderst, R., and M. Ottaviani. 2011. How (Not) to Pay for Advice: A Framework for Consumer
Financial Protection. mimeo, Northwestern University.
Insurance Regulatory and Development Authority (IRDA) of India. 2010. Annual Report.
Kumar, Jagendra, 2009. “Lapsation of a Life Insurance Policy,” Bimaquest, 9(2): 38-44.
Mullainathan, S., M. Noth, and A. Schoar. 2010. The Market for Financial Advice: An Audit
Study, mimeo, Harvard University.
Rajagopalan, R. 2010. Comparing Traditional Life Insurance Products in the Indian Market: A
Consumer Perspective, mimeo, CORE Centre, India.
Stango, V. and J. Zinman. 2009. Exponential Growth Bias and Household Finance. Journal of
Finance 64(6): 2807-49.
Woodward, S. 2008. Consumer Confusion in the Mortgage Market, Manuscript, Sand Hill Econo-
metrics.
32
10 Appendix
11 Model of a Dominated Financial Product
11.1 Monopolist Insurance Company
The monopolist has three possible options. One option is to offer only term insurance. If he chooses
this option he chooses prices and commissions to maximize:
max
{p
t
,c
t
}
s(p
t
c
t
k)(α p
t
) + c
t
(p
t
c
t
k)(α p
t
)
The first order condition with respect to price p
t
is (s+c
t
)(p
t
c
t
k)(1)+(s+c
t
)(αp
t
) = 0,
which simplifies to p
t
=
α+k+c
t
2
. The first order condition with respect to c
t
is (s + c
t
)(p
t
α) +
(αp
t
αkp
2
t
c
t
α+kp
t
+c
t
p
t
) = 0. Solving this system of equations yields the solution c
t
=
αk2s
3
and p
t
=
2α+ks
3
. Note that we need s
αk
2
to guarantee that commissions are non-negative (this
condition also guarantees that prices are non-negative).
13
The monopolist’s second option is to offer both term and whole insurance. This option
essentially constitutes price discrimination, where low prices and zero commissions are associated
with term insurance for sophisticated consumers, and high prices and commissions are associated
with whole insurance and unsophisticated consumers. The firm will pay zero commissions for the
sale of term insurance; paying commissions does not increase demand but it does increase costs.
The monopolist firm chooses the term insurance price p
t
to maximize s(p
t
k)(α p
t
). The first
order condition for p
t
is α 2p
t
+ k = 0. The firm will choose to charge a price
α+k
2
for term
insurance. Total profits from the sale of term insurance will equal
s(αk)
2
4
.
The firm will pay positive commissions for the sale of whole insurance, because demand is
increasing in commissions. The firm maximizes the total profit function from selling whole insurance
to unsophisticated customers: c
w
(p
w
k c
w
)(α p
w
). The first order condition with respect to
price is c
w
α 2p
w
c
w
+ c
w
k + c
2
w
= 0. The first order condition with respect to the commission
level c
w
is c
w
( kα 2 p
2
+ pk + 2cp) = 0. Solving these two first order conditions we find
that the firm will set the whole insurance price (p
w
) equal to
1
3
(2α + k) and will pay commissions
13
Intuitively, this condition rules out a situation where there are a large number of sophisticated consumers and
thus the firm would choose to pay negative commissions (i.e. force agents to pay the firm for selling to sophisticated
consumers). If commissions were negative, agents would have no incentive to sell insurance in this model.
33
1
3
(α k).
We now show that when both products are offered and prices and commissions are chosen
separately for each, that the price of term insurance will be higher than the price of whole insurance:
α + k
2
<
1
3
(2α + k)
This expression can be simplified to α > k, which must be true for their to be any positive
demand for either insurance product. Thus, the monopolist will always choose higher prices for the
whole insurance product versus the term insurance product. Intuitively, the monopolist pays higher
commissions on whole insurance to attract consumers, and then passes on those commissions as
higher prices. Total profits from the sale of whole insurance under the price discrimination strategy
is
(αk)
3
27
. Total profits from the strategy of offering both term and whole products is
s(αk)
2
4
+
(αk)
3
27
.
The monopolist’s third option is to offer only whole insurance. The sophisticated types never
buy this, and the chosen p
w
and c
w
would be equivalent to those in Case 2. Thus, the firm can
always add term insurance paying zero commissions and increase its profits. Thus, the monopolist
firm will never offer only whole insurance.
We now show that the monopolist firm will always choose to offer both products as opposed to
offering just term insurance. Intuitively, the monopolist can offer term and whole insurance products
to price discriminate amongst the two types of consumers. In this case, price discrimination takes
the form of offering higher commissions for sales of whole insurance to unsophisticated customers,
and commissions equal to zero for sales of term insurance to sophisticated customers. We begin
by showing that the profits from term consumers will always be lower when only term insurance is
offered versus when both term insurance and whole insurance are offered.
The total profits from selling term insurance when both products are offered is
s(αk)
2
4
. The
total profit from sophisticated consumers when only term insurance is offered is s[
1
3
(2α + k s)
1
3
(α k 2s)][α
1
3
(2α + k s)]. We wish to show that:
s(α k)
2
4
> s[
1
3
(2α + k s) k
1
3
(α k 2s)][α
1
3
(2α + k s)]
(α k)
2
4
>
1
9
(α k + s)
2
34
Taking the square root of both sides we have
αk
2
>
1
3
(α k +s) which simplifies to
αk
2
s.
Note that this is the same condition we needed to guarantee that commissions and prices are
positive. Thus, the profits from selling to sophisticated consumers will be higher when both term
and whole insurance products are offered, with different commissions and prices, then when term
is sold to all customers.
We now show that the profits from unsophisticated consumers are also higher when the
price discrimination strategy is followed. The profits on unsophisticated consumers under the price
discrimination strategy are
(αk)
3
27
. The total profits from unsophisticated consumers when only
term insurance is offered are [
1
3
(α k 2s)
1
3
(α 2s)][α
1
3
(2α s)]. Simplification shows that
the price discrimination strategy yields higher profits as long as 3(α k) + 2s > 0, which must be
true as both α k and s are non-negative.
Thus, we have shown that a monopolist firm will choose to sell both term and whole insurance,
at different prices, to sophisticated and unsophisticated customers respectively. We have also shown
that the monopolist will choose higher prices and commissions for whole insurance than for term
insurance.
11.2 Two Competing Insurance Companies
The setup of this problem is defined in the Conclusion and Discussion section of the main text. We
first solve for firm i’s optimal behavior given firm j’s possible behavior. Suppose firm j only offers
whole insurance paying commission c
j
and charging price p
j
. In this case firm i will always choose
to sell both whole and term insurance. If he chose to sell only one of these products, he could
increase his profits by entering the term insurance market as a monopoly provider. Thus, there
cannot be an equilibrium where both firms only sell either only term insurance or whole insurance.
Now suppose firm j offers both term and whole insurance. We show that there is one possible
equilibrium in this case. Bertrand competition in the market for term insurance gives a Nash
equilibrium p
i,t
= p
j,t
= k. In the term insurance market prices get driven down to marginal cost.
Competition in the market for term insurance leads to lower prices, as sophisticated consumers are
not persuaded by commissions in their decisions to purchase insurance products.
We now solve for a Nash equilibrium in the market for whole insurance. A price and com-
missions pair (c
1
, p
1
, c
2
, p
2
) is a Nash equilibrium in the market for whole insurance if (c
i
, p
i
), for
35
each firm i, solves the following problem (we suppress w subscript, but the commission and price
term refer to whole insurance):
max
c
i
,p
i
(c
i
bc
j
)(p
i
k c
i
)(α p
i
)
The first order condition with respect to p
i
can be simplified to:
1
2
(p
i
k+bc
j
). The first order
condition with respect to c
i
an be simplified to c
i
=
1
2
(p
i
k + bc
j
). Solving these two equations
in two unknowns we find that firm i’s optimal choices given firm j’s choices are: c
i
=
αk+2bc
j
3
and
p
i
=
1
3
(2α + k + bc
j
). In a Nash equilibrium, firm j plays the same best responses given firm i’s
behavior, and thus we have: c
j
=
αk+2bc
i
3
and p
j
=
1
3
(2α + k + bc
i
).
Solving this system of equations we find that the Nash equilibrium commissions are c
i
=
c
j
=
αk
32b
, and the Nash equilibrium prices are p
i
= p
j
=
(2b)α+(1b)k
32b
. Note that for commissions
and prices to be positive we need b
3
2
.
It is clear from the expression c
i
= c
j
=
αk
32b
that the level of commissions paid will increase
in the degree to which the insurance products compete with each other (b). We now show that
prices are also increasing in b. We wish to show that the derivative of the expression for equilibrium
prices with respect to b is greater than zero:
(3 2b)
1
(α k) (3 2b)
2
((2 b)α + (1 b)k) > 0
This expression can be simplified to α > k, which must be true for there to be any positive
demand for the insurance product.
36
Figure 1 plots the fraction of agents each week recommending ULIP products to our mystery
shoppers. The day the reform went into effect, July 1, 2010, is indicated by a red line.
Number of
Audits Auditors Agents
Panel A: Competition (City #1)
By need, belief, and source of beliefs (competition)
Need Term Bias Term Recommendation from other Agent 61 4 57
Need Term Bias Term Recommendation from friend 65 4 61
Need Term Bias Whole Recommendation from other Agent 57 5 53
Need Term Bias Whole Recommendation from friend 75 4 70
Need Whole Bias Term Recommendation from other Agent 77 4 70
Need Whole Bias Term Recommendation from friend 77 4 71
Need Whole Bias Whole Recommendation from other Agent 68 4 62
Need Whole Bias Whole Recommendation from friend 77 5 73
Total
a
557 304
Panel B: Disclosure Experiment (City #2)
By timing and whether auditor inquired about commission
Ask about commission Pre-Disclosure Requirement 82 4 67
Ask about commission Post-Disclosure Requirement 61 3 58
Do not ask about commission Pre-Disclosure Requirement 67 4 54
Do not ask about commission Post-Disclosure Requirement 47 3 40
Total
a
257 198
Panel C: Sophistication Experiment (City #2)
By level of sophistication
Low level of sophistication 114 7 110
High level of sophistication 103 6 103
Total
a
217 209
Table 1: Audit Counts
Table 1 contains audit counts from our three experiments, disaggregated by treatment combinations. The first column provides the total
number of audits for each treatment combination, the second column provides the total number of auditors involved for each treatment
combination, and the final column provides the number of distinct agents visited for each treatment combination. Quality of Advice refers
to the experiment where we varied the auditor's needs, beliefs, and the source of their beliefs (competing agent or friend). Disclosure refers
to the experiment where we varied whether the auditor made a disclosure inquiry, both before and after the mandatory disclosure law, to test
the law's effect on agent behavior. Sophistication refers to the experiment where we varied the auditors' expressed financial sophistication.
a) Since agents may have been visited by more than one auditor, the number of agents visited is less than the total number of audits.
Quality of Advice Disclosure Sophistication
LIC Underwriter 0.73 0.50 0.69
(0.44) (0.50) (0.46)
Audit Location
Agent Home 0.18 0.14 0.12
(0.39) (0.34) (0.33)
Agent Office 0.12 0.72 0.55
(0.33) (0.45) (0.50)
Auditor Home 0.01 0.06 0.03
(0.09) (0.23) (0.18)
Auditor Office 0.01 0.02 0.18
(0.12) (0.12) (0.39)
Other Venue 0.68 0.07 0.11
(0.47) (0.26) (0.31)
Audit Duration 37.13 37.58 33.22
(10.22) (15.88) (12.58)
Recommendations:
Only Whole 0.81 0.25 0.75
(0.39) (0.43) (0.43)
Only Term 0.03 0.01 0.14
(0.17) (0.09) (0.35)
Only ULIP 0.08 0.71 0.16
(0.27) (0.45) (0.37)
Any Whole 0.90 0.27 0.82
(0.30) (0.44) (0.38)
Any Term 0.13 0.01 0.22
(0.33) (0.11) (0.42)
Any ULIP 0.10 0.72 0.18
(0.30) (0.45) (0.38)
Observations 557 257 217
Table 2: Summary Statistics From Audits
Table 2 presents summary statistics from our three experiments. Quality of Advice refers to the
experiment where we varied the auditor's needs (savings vs. risk), beliefs (whole vs. term) and
the source of their beliefs (competing agent or friend). Disclosure refers to the experiment where
we varied whether the auditor made a disclosure inquiry, both before and after the mandatory
disclosure law, to test the law's effect on agent behavior. Sophistication refers to the experiment
where we varied the auditors' expressed financial sophistication. Note that "LIC" refers to the
Life Insurance Corporation of India, a government-owned insurance company that has the largest
share of insurers in the country.
Term Whole Term Whole Friend Agent Inquiry
No Inquiry
Low High
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
Government Underwriter 0.82 0.79 0.79 0.82 0.80 0.82 0.50 0.55 0.72 0.71
LIC Underwriter 0.74 0.73 0.71 0.76 0.73 0.74 0.48 0.52 0.68 0.70
Agent is Male 0.84 0.84 0.86 0.83 0.84 0.84 0.88 0.93 0.89 0.93
Agent Dress (1-simple to 5-sophisticated) 4.07 4.03 4.05 4.05 4.11 3.98 ** 3.60 3.53
Physical Quality of Office (1-low to 5-high) 4.18 4.19 4.13 4.23 4.19 4.18 3.57 3.69
Audit Location
Agent Home 0.19 0.18 0.17 0.19 0.16 0.21 0.17 0.10 * 0.11 0.14
Agent Office 0.13 0.11 0.12 0.12 0.13 0.11 0.69 0.75 0.53 0.58
Auditor Home 0.00 0.02 ** 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03
Auditor Office 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.04 ** 0.18 0.18
Other Venue 0.67 0.68 0.69 0.66 0.69 0.66 0.08 0.06 0.15 0.07 *
Audits 280 277 258 299 294 263 143 114 114 103
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 3: Tests of Randomization
Table 3 presents summary statistics from our three experiments disaggregated by treatment. They are used to perform randomization checks, univariate regressions (with robust
standard errors) of the treatment on each independent variable. Significant differences are denoted by asterisks. Quality of Advice refers to the experiment where we varied the
auditor's needs (suitability ), beliefs (bias) , and the source of their beliefs, competing agent or friend (competition ). As mentioned in Table 1, Disclosure refers to the experiment
where we varied whether the auditor made a disclosure inquiry, both before and after the mandatory disclosure law, to test the law's effect on agent behavior. Sophistication refers
to the experiment where we varied the auditors' expressed financial sophistication. Note that "Government Underwriter" includes LIC, State Bank of India (SBI), United Trust of
India (UTI), and the Industrial Development Bank of India (IDBI).
Quality of Advice
Disclosure
Sophistication
Bias Treatment
Suitability
Treatment
Competition
Treatment
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Bias=Term 0.096 *** 0.105 *** 0.019 * 0.022 ** 0.131 ** 0.125 ** -0.013 -0.019
(0.029) (0.028) (0.011) (0.011) (0.060) (0.058) (0.050) (0.045)
Need=Term 0.116 *** 0.126 *** 0.015 0.019 * 0.170 ** 0.177 ** 0.002 -0.005
(0.032) (0.031) (0.011) (0.011) (0.075) (0.075) (0.051) (0.048)
(Bias=Term)*(Need=Term) 0.021 0.006 0.053 * 0.049 * 0.055 0.051 0.043 0.038
(0.057) (0.055) (0.030) (0.028) (0.128) (0.127) (0.065) (0.060)
Government Underwriter -0.121 *** -0.017 -0.222 ** -0.039
Audit Location
(0.039) (0.021) (0.094) (0.050)
Agent Home 0.012 -0.021 -0.069 -0.113
(0.047) (0.027) (0.105) (0.071)
Auditor Home -0.132 -0.018 -0.499 * -0.673
(0.105) (0.026) (0.282) (0.517)
Auditor Office 0.329 ** 0.206 0.315 -0.554 ***
(0.155) (0.140) (0.250) (0.212)
Other Venue -0.018 -0.018 -0.081 -0.122 **
(0.041) (0.022) (0.089) (0.052)
Auditor Fixed Effects No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
Observations 557 557 557 557 538 538 540 540
Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Any Term
Only Term
Ln(Coverage)
Ln(Premium)
Table 4 reports regressions where the dependent variables are the (exclusive) presence of term insurance in the agent’s recommendation in columns (1) - (4). The
dependent variable is the logarithm of risk coverage recommended in Columns (5) and (6) and of premium amount recommended in Columns (7) and (8) . The main
independent variables are whether the auditor expressed a bias for term, whether the auditor expressed a genuine need for term, and an interaction between these two
variables. The bias for term is expressed through an auditor’s explicit stated preference for term, while a need for term is expressed by the auditor mentioning his/her desire
to cover risk at an affordable cost (as opposed to the need for whole, which is expressed by wanting to save and invest and not feeling self-disciplined enough to do it on
one’s own). Dummy variables for venue location (agent office is the omitted category), whether the agent was selling insurance from a government underwriter, and auditor
fixed effects are also included in columns (2), (4), (6), and (8). The number of observations in Columns (5) and (6) are less than those in (1) and (2) because agents did not
recommend specific levels of coverage in 19 audits.
Table 4: Do Agents Cater to Customers Beliefs or Respond to Customer Needs?
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Dependent Variable
Bias=Term 0.105 *** 0.106 *** 0.091 ** 0.090 ** 0.043 *** 0.045 *** 0.026 0.027
(0.028) (0.027) (0.041) (0.038) (0.014) (0.014) (0.018) (0.017)
Need=Term 0.127 *** 0.130 *** 0.067 * 0.068 * 0.042 *** 0.044 *** 0.027 0.029
(0.028) (0.027) (0.038) (0.035) (0.015) (0.014) (0.019) (0.020)
Competition 0.024 0.033 -0.011 -0.008 0.010 0.012 0.000 0.001
(0.028) (0.027) (0.023) (0.024) (0.014) (0.014) (0.006)
(Bias=Term)*Competition 0.011 0.030 -0.013 -0.008
(0.057) (0.056) (0.022) (0.022)
(Need=Term)*Competition 0.111 * 0.135 ** -0.027 -0.023
(0.067) (0.067) (0.019) (0.021)
(Bias=Term)*(Need=Term) 0.062 0.075 -0.006 -0.004
(0.076) (0.071) (0.037) (0.036)
(Bias=Term)*(Need=Term)*Competition -0.095 -0.158 0.125 ** 0.113 **
(0.115) (0.113) (0.059) (0.055)
Government Underwriter -0.122 *** -0.128 *** -0.020 -0.013
Audit Location
(0.039) (0.039) (0.021) (0.020)
Agent Home 0.009 0.002 -0.022 -0.019
(0.047) (0.047) (0.028) (0.027)
Auditor Home -0.138 -0.140 -0.018 -0.015
(0.108) (0.112) (0.029) (0.025)
Auditor Office 0.331 ** 0.332 ** 0.207 0.202
(0.156) (0.158) (0.139) (0.137)
Other Venue -0.020 -0.028 -0.022 -0.016
(0.040) (0.040) (0.023) (0.022)
Auditor Fixed Effects No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
Observations 557 557 557 557 557 557 557 557
Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Recommended Any Term
Recommended Only Term
Table 5 reports regressions where the dependent variables are the (exclusive) presence of term insurance in the agent’s recommendation. The main independent variable is competition (the
main effect and the interactions with bias and need), which is signaled in an audit in two ways: first, by the auditor mentioning meeting with other providers and second, by the auditor stating a
preference based on advice from another agent. Dummy variables for venue location (agent office is the omitted category), whether the agent was selling insurance from a government
underwriter, and auditor fixed effects are also included in even-numbered columns
Table 5: Does the Presence of Competition Improve Agent Advice?
Overall Pre-Regulation Post-Regulation Difference
LIC Underwriter 0.50 0.44 0.58 0.15 ***
Audit Location
(0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.06)
Agent Home 0.14 0.09 0.19 0.10 ***
(0.34) (0.29) (0.40) (0.05)
Agent Office 0.72 0.75 0.67 -0.09 *
(0.45) (0.43) (0.47) (0.06)
Auditor Home 0.06 0.07 0.04 -0.04
(0.23) (0.26) (0.19) (0.03)
Auditor Office 0.02 0.02 0.01 -0.01
(0.12) (0.14) (0.10) (0.01)
Other Venue 0.07 0.06 0.09 0.03 **
(0.26) (0.24) (0.29) (0.03)
Audit Duration 37.58 36.14 39.56 3.41 ***
(15.88) (14.33) (17.67) (2.07)
Recommendations:
Only Whole 0.25 0.15 0.39 0.24 ***
(0.43) (0.36) (0.49) (0.06)
Only Term 0.01 0.01 0.00 -0.01
(0.09) (0.12) (0.00) (0.01)
Only ULIP 0.71 0.83 0.55 -0.29 ***
(0.45) (0.37) (0.50) (0.06)
Any Whole 0.27 0.15 0.43 0.27 ***
(0.44) (0.36) (0.50) (0.06)
Any Term 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00
(0.11) (0.12) (0.10) (0.01)
Any ULIP 0.72 0.83 0.56 -0.28 ***
(0.45) (0.37) (0.50) (0.06)
Observations 257 149 108
Table 6: Disclosure Experiment Summary Statistics
Table 6 presents summary statistics from the disclosure experiment disaggregated by timing. They are used
to perform a balance check, univariate regressions (with robust standard errors) of the treatment on each
independent variable. Significant differences are denoted by asterisks.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Dependent Variable: Ln(Risk Cover) Ln(Premium)
Sample: All All
Government
Underwriter
Private
Underwriter
All All
Post Disclosure -0.25 *** -0.19 ** -0.30 ** -0.07 0.15 0.03
(0.09) (0.08) (0.12) (0.08) (0.13) (0.07)
Disclosure Inquiry 0.05 0.02 0.07 0.00 0.02 0.00
(0.06) (0.06) (0.13) (0.05) (0.11) (0.06)
Post * (Disclosure Inquiry) -0.06 -0.02 -0.06 0.07 0.02 -0.01
(0.12) (0.10) (0.17) (0.11) (0.17) (0.09)
Government Underwriter -0.42 *** 0.29 *** 0.01
Audit Location
(0.05) (0.10) (0.05)
Agent Home -0.01 -0.02 0.07 * 0.06 0.04
(0.08) (0.10) (0.04) (0.12) (0.08)
Auditor Home -0.02 -0.25 0.03 0.65 * 0.24
(0.11) (0.16) (0.05) (0.37) (0.21)
Auditor Office 0.18 0.65 *** 0.05 0.62 *** 0.30 *
(0.13) (0.12) (0.05) (0.19) (0.17)
Other Venue 0.06 0.04 0.06 * 0.07 -0.01
(0.09) (0.13) (0.04) (0.14) (0.07)
Auditor Fixed Effects No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 257 257 134 134 214 214
Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
ULIP Recommendation
Table 7: Disclosure Regulations and Product Recommendations
Table 7 reports regressions where the dependent variable is a binary equal to 1 if a ULIP product is recommended for columns (1) -(4). The dependent
variable in columns (5) and (6) are, respectively, the logarithm of the risk coverage and premium of the recommended policy. The ULIP product is the
product where disclosure of commissions was made mandatory on July 1, 2010. The main independent variables are whether or not the audit occurred after
the commissions disclosure law came into effect (post disclosure ), whether or not the auditor made an explicit commission disclosure inquiry , and an
interaction between these two variables. Dummy variables for venue location (agent office is omitted), whether the agent is selling insurance from a
government-owned insurer, and auditor fixed-effects are included in even-numbered columns.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Sophisticated 0.10 * 0.10 * 0.02 0.03 0.22 * 0.21 * -0.03 -0.06
(0.06) (0.06) (0.05) (0.05) (0.12) (0.12) (0.09) (0.10)
Government Underwriter -0.08 -0.09 -0.25 0.05
Audit Location
(0.07) (0.06) (0.16) (0.10)
Agent Home 0.10 -0.01 0.21 -0.21
(0.10) (0.06) (0.18) (0.18)
Auditor Home 0.02 -0.11 ** 0.32 0.03
(0.14) (0.05) (0.29) (0.14)
Auditor Office 0.13 0.13 0.20 -0.17
(0.09) (0.09) (0.16) (0.13)
Other Venue -0.01 0.06 -0.17 -0.28
(0.09) (0.09) (0.24) (0.19)
Auditor Fixed Effects No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
Observations 217 217 217 217 209 209 209 209
Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Recommended Any Term
Recommended Only Term
Ln(Coverage)
Ln(Premium)
Table 8: Effect of Sophistication on Quality of Advice
Table 8 reports regressions where the dependent variables are the (exclusive) presence of term insurance in the agent’s recommendation. The main independent variable
is whether or not the audit is part of the “sophisticated” treatment group. Sophistication was signaled to the agent by a script in which auditors mentioned how they had
been shopping around and were aware of the different types of policies (such as ULIPs, term, etc.) In unsophisticated audits, auditors acknowledged that life insurance
was complex but admitted to knowing very little about the types of policies. Dummy variables for auditor identity, venue location, and whether the government
purveyed/underwrote the insurance policy are also included in the even-numbered columns.
Panel A: Life Insurance Products
Whole Life Insurance Term Life Insurance
Government and private insurance companies
Government and private insurance
companies
Specific Plan Example The Whole Life Plan (#2) Amulya Jeevan (#190)
Firm Offering Life Insurance Corporation of India (LIC) Life Insurance Corporation of India (LIC)
Coverage Amount 2,500,000 4,000,000
Premium for 25 year old male Rs. 55,116 Rs. 11,996
Years client pays 47 35
Years policy pays out until death of client, no matter the age 35
Historic bonus percentage 7% (non-compounded) n/a
Panel B: Savings Products
Promised interest rate
Bank Fixed Deposit 8.75%
Government Provident Fund 8%
Panel C: Comparison of Whole Life vs. Term and Fixed Deposit Savings
Whole Life Insurance Term + Savings
Products Purchased
Rs. 2.5m in life insurance at Rs. 55,166 per
year for 47 years
Rs. 4m of term life insurance for 35 years,
at annual payments of 11,996 per year for
35 years.
Savings deposit of Rs 55,166-
11,996=43,170 per year for 35 years,
earning 8.75%
Savings deposit of Rs. 55,166 per year
from years 36-47, earning 8.75%
Value Upon Death (Rs.) Whole Payout
Term Payout (if any) + Savings
Dying at age: 25 2,675,000 4,046,893
35 4,425,000 4,812,490
45 6,175,000 6,583,792
55 7,925,000 10,779,449
65 9,675,000 16,584,940
75 11,425,000 39,271,154
85 13,175,000 91,310,405
Appendix Table A1: Comparison of Whole vs. Term Plus Savings
Bias treatment
Bias towards term Bias towards whole
Text of statement
“I have heard from [source] that term
insurance is a really good product.
“I have heard from [source] that whole
insurance is a really good product.
Needs treatment
Need term Need whole
Text of Statement
“I am worried that if I die early, my wife and
kids will not be able to live comfortably or
meet our financial obligations. I want to cover
that risk at an affordable cost.”
"I want to save and invest money for the
future, and I also want to make sure my wife
and children will be taken care of if I die. I do
not have the discipline to save on my own.”
Competition Treatment
High Competition Low Competition
Competition
"I have already met with some providers, but
would like to learn more about the specific
products your firm offers so I can make a
comparison" [source] in bias statement is
“another agent”
"What are the different products that you
offer?" [source] in bias statement is “friends”
Knowledge treatment
Knowledge of Commissions No Knowledge
“Can you give me more information about the
commission charges I’ll be paying?”
No mention of commission charges
Sophistication treatment
Sophisticated Unsophisticated
“In the past, I have spent time shopping for
the policies, and am perhaps surprisingly
somewhat familiar with the different types of
policies: ULIPs, term, whole life insurance.
However, I am less familiar with the specific
policies that your firm offers, so I was hoping
you can walk me through them and
recommend a policy specific for my
situation.”
“I am aware of the complexities of Life
Insurance Products and I don’t understand
them very much; however I am interested in
purchasing a policy. Would you help me with
this?”
Quality of Advice Experiment
Disclosure Experiment
Sophistication Experiment
Appendix Table A2 Text of Treatments